Pretty much everyone involved in the
legal profession in any meaningful way spends much if not most of his/her time
trying to allocate costs. Whether you’re a judge structuring a judgment or
consent decree, a litigator structuring a settlement, a transactional attorney
structuring a deal, or a legislator or regulator structuring new rules or laws,
you’re inevitably left with the fundamental question: “Who is going to bear the
cost?” Indeed, any transaction between two or more parties (and even parties
acting alone, if you consider externalities) implicates questions of cost
distribution.
This is why it is absolutely
mind-boggling to me that law firms – ostensibly the veritable pinnacles of rationality
and enlightened self-interest – overwhelmingly employ a direct billable-hour
model, a model which creates perverse incentives and uncritically distributes
costs inefficiently and inequitably.
O, let me count the ways:
First, billable hours create perverse
incentives. Hourly wages are reasonable for jobs which consist in substantial
part in presence (i.e., security guard, cashier, etc.), since that part of the job cannot
be made more or less efficient. For professional, skilled labor, hourly wages
create a tension between skill (a function of quality and efficiency) and
financial incentive (the slower you work, the more you earn). Law firms,
doubtless realizing this, pay salary rather than wages. This might have been a
valid approach, granting arguendo that
market forces would prevent firms from intentionally hiring slow lawyers, if
there were no billable-hour targets for individual attorneys and if their bonuses
weren’t contingent on billable milestones.
Second, billable hours are hugely inefficient. Economists
often talk about things having diminishing
marginal value, meaning that each consecutive unit of that thing is worth
less than the one before. The standard example is money: another $100 is worth
a lot when you have $1000, but very little when you have $100,000. Of course,
labor is the flip-side of capital, so the more you’ve already worked, the less work
you’ll ordinarily be willing to do for the same pay – consider the difference
between your third consecutive hour working on something and your ninth. Because
hourly billing does not account for this, clients can be effectively timeline-indifferent:
starting a 40-hour project two weeks
in advance costs the same as starting it two days in advance. The individual attorney, on the other hand, would
of course rather bill four hours per day over the course of 10 days than 20 hours
per day two days in a row. This results in what economists call deadweight loss – the difference between
what-it’s-worth-to-you (the fair market value) and what-you-actually-pay –
since the attorney works more highly-valued hours (hours five through 20 on
each of two days) than he/she would have otherwise, and that difference in
value doesn’t flow as gain to either the client or the firm. This is textbook
inefficiency. (Alternatively, the firm could take on the cost of scrambling
several attorneys to each work four to eight hours on both days. In this case,
the inefficiency harms the firm instead of the lawyer while the client remains indifferent.)
Third, billable hours create all kinds of
externalities and financial and non-financial costs. Because billable targets
are high, individual
attorneys can’t turn away clients, and clients tend to spring large projects at
the last possible moment (or later), lawyers work ridiculous hours. This
imposes physical and mental health costs on them, social and emotional costs on
their families, and human capital costs on the firms (on the one hand, attrition
due to burnout, and on the other, the opulence necessary to convince associates
that life is still worth living). Indeed, the externalities reach the
profession itself – lawyers are significantly more likely than any other
professionals (probably even rock stars) to be substance abusers.
Now, I’m not sure that market forces can
solve every problem. But it seems to me that in this case, shifting some of the
costs back onto the client would do everyone involved a world of good. And that
includes the clients, since law firms inevitably have to drive up prices to
cover the costs to them and offer salaries high enough to convince people to
subject themselves to the almighty billable hour. I cannot imagine it being all
that difficult to figure out a way to charge a premium for expedited or
otherwise high-stress, high-intensity work. And again, the goal is not to
reduce the amount of work, but simply to smooth out the workload over time,
thereby mitigating the diminishing marginal value problem.
Come on now, law firms – chop chop!
No comments:
Post a Comment